The 24-hour news cycle is causing a cacophony of
speculation about Greece leaving the euro, the so-called Grexit. Amid all the
arguments about whether Greece will or should exit, there has been a lot less
thought given to what would happen if Greece does return to the drachma. It’s
time to think more seriously about this possibility.
If the Greek people choose to leave in a referendum,
they will send a powerful signal that they, and not the central bankers,
officials and politicians in Frankfurt, Brussels and Berlin hold the destiny of
the euro in their hands. But if it’s the Greek politicians who make the
decision to leave, based on an electoral mandate rather than a referendum, that
could make voters elsewhere think twice before voting for antiausterity
candidates.
There will be lessons for politicians about the
dangers of brinkmanship, especially if a Grexit happens almost by accident. If
the funding problems facing the government and the banks escalate out of
control, capital controls would be triggered, making a vote on Greece’s future
-whether by Parliamentary elections or a referendum- far more likely.
Politicians in smaller economies might in future be more likely to cut a deal
with creditors, and politicians in creditor countries might be more likely to
offer better deals, including debt relief. After all, Greece would almost
certainly unilaterally default on its debts when it leaves.
Meanwhile, a Grexit would resolve the uncertainty over
how to leave the single currency. The euro wasn’t designed with an easily
accessible escape hatch. If Greece does leave, it will establish a precedent,
but not one that others may wish to emulate, since it might also have to leave
the European Union too.
Most important of all, a Grexit might set an economic
precedent. If the Greek economy should recover after leaving the eurozone, it
would be much harder to convince others that they should stay.
However, a painful economic afterlife seems far more
likely. The Greek economy would get caught in a pincer, with a sharp and
sustained contraction in credit and an increase in uncertainty propelling the
economy back into a deep recession. There would be a significant risk of
further, lasting damage to the Greek economy through the destruction of jobs
and companies.
Even the sharp depreciation in the currency would be a
double-edged sword. There would be a painful squeeze on disposable income as
imports become much more expensive. This would at least partly offset the boost
to Greek exports, assuming companies elsewhere in the eurozone don’t reroute
supply chains out of Greece to avoid invoices billed in drachma. Likewise, it
is brave to assume that there would be an influx of foreign capital until the
political and economic uncertainty has been resolved.
Greece would also be giving up the long-run benefits
of euro membership, such as increased trade and competition, a more-efficient
allocation of resources, a greater capacity to insure against risk that comes
from unfettered access to European markets, and the greater stability that
comes from delegating the conduct of economic policy to more effective
institutions outside of Athens. The complexity of creating credible
domestic-policy institutions in the aftermath of a Grexit shouldn’t be
underestimated.
Beyond these near-term challenges, there are two
important medium-term consequences to consider.
A post-Grexit eurozone would be more susceptible to
the kind of speculative attack on the currency union that took place in 2012.
Given a resumption of sovereign stress in smaller countries, investors would
quickly start to demand sizeable compensation for the risk that they may not be
paid in euros in a future break-up scenario. Spending would grind to a halt and
capital would fly out of the countries concerned.
The European Central Bank’s most potent policy tool,
its quantitative easing program, isn’t designed to deal with this problem, and
the instrument that is -the Outright Monetary Transactions program to buy a
small set of sovereign bonds in the secondary market- may not be big enough to
stabilize markets in a future crisis. The OMT can only be used to save
countries that commit to saving themselves by driving through reforms.
We should expect a political response to fight those
forces threatening to pull the eurozone apart. A Grexit could ultimately bring
the union closer together, with fiscal union and common debt issuance going
hand in hand with binding and credible commitments on structural reforms
helping to turn the eurozone into an optimal and far more stable currency area.
This is all moot if Greece’s leaders hammer out a deal
with creditors and avert an exit from the eurozone. But prudent policy makers
and investors should spend some time considering how they would answer some of
the questions that a Grexit might raise.
Δεν υπάρχουν σχόλια:
Δημοσίευση σχολίου