Maybe
Greece had a point. That seems to be the subtext of many high-profile
pronouncements made by European politicians and technocrats in recent days.
These alliances are fluid. At times this
year it looked like the whole of Europe was ranged against Greece. But this was
more a product of the extreme negotiating stance adopted by Athens and the
survival instincts of southern European governments (who didn’t want to provide
succour to anti-austerity movements in their own countries). Deep-seated
convictions were temporarily held in abeyance.
But, in the brief pause between Greece
agreeing fresh terms with its creditors and holding elections, the two sides
are once again coalescing around the separate solutions they believe will
strengthen the eurozone.
This is not about being pro or
anti-austerity; that gross over-simplification was always a red herring. It is
about ensuring that countries don’t reap the benefits of the currency union
while shirking their shared responsibilities. The difference of opinion lies in
identifying where the benefits accrue and defining what the responsibilities
should be. Both factions have a case.
One answer is that the eurozone is a currency union of economically
independent nations whose stability can only be maintained by the strict
adherence to a number of hard and fast rules. Among the most important of these
proscribes permanent fiscal transfers between member states. That’s because, so
the argument goes, such subsidies blur the lines between sovereign nations and
introduce political union via the backdoor.
Critics of this argument say the rules are
too harsh. They result in the richer nations enjoying the benefits of a
currency union (like, for example, an artificially depressed currency that
boosts the competitiveness of their exports), while the poorer nations are
denied the tools to rebalance their economies if crisis hits. On this reading
the rich nations enjoy most of the benefits of the currency union in the good
times and the poor nations suffer most of the drawbacks when the weather turns.
The only way to redress this balance is through fiscal transfers.
It is
hard to tell which view is in the ascendancy. On the one hand, Greece clearly
caved in to its creditors’ demands and agreed to institute a raft of economic
reforms, including exacting primary surplus targets. This can be seen as a
victory for those who champion the European Union’s strict debt and deficit
rules. On the other hand, by agreeing to lessen Greece’s debt burden, the other
member states are taking the first step towards turning the eurozone into a
transfer union.
A eurozone defined by strict rules has the
merits of being what all the various countries signed up to. On the downside,
it could be argued that, with the bloc’s youth unemployment at 21.9pc in July,
it is an imperfect set-up. A transfer union might work better (though there are
plenty of people living in the north of England who will argue against it being
a panacea) but would necessitate a far greater degree of fiscal and political
integration.
That is exactly what so many European
politicians have been falling over themselves to argue for in recent days.
First, Italy’s finance minister, Pier Carlo Padoan, called for a full political
union. Then Emmanuel Macron, the French economy minister, writing in Germany’s
Süddeustche Zeitung newspaper over the weekend, called for a full fiscal union
and a new “Euro Parliament”. He said: “The eurozone needs new institutions to
which national governments transfer sovereignty: a strong European economic
government with its own budget.”
It is not hard to imagine how all of this is
going down in Berlin. In recent months Wolfgang Schaeuble, the German finance
minister, has been agitating in the opposite direction, arguing that what he
sees as an increasingly-partisan European Commission should be stripped of some
of its powers.
German politicians are unlikely to be
surprised by their French and Italian counterparts calling for the
strengthening of European institutions. Arguably, it will have been last week’s
speech by Benoît Cœuré - a Frenchman, yes, but also a member of the European Central
Bank’s executive board - that caused more consternation.
He argued for the creation of a finance
ministry for the eurozone, saying: “I want to make this clear: we cannot
advocate a Europe of solidarity while believing that the economic policies of each
euro area country are the business of that country’s parliament alone. The
crisis has fully exposed that contradiction.”
So, poor, defeated Greece may in fact end up
getting what it was demanding. There is, of course, a further paradox here. The
Greek government argued that the January election and July referendum gave it a
democratic mandate to reject the terms of the country’s bailout.
In so doing, it was implicitly arguing that
the eurozone should become a transfer union in which the richer countries help
subsidise poorer regions. If that argument wins out, it will end up diminishing
the individual sovereignty of the eurozone member states and hence their
democratic mandates. It’s like turkeys voting to be disenfranchised.
Πηγή:
telegraph.co.uk
Δεν υπάρχουν σχόλια:
Δημοσίευση σχολίου