Europe’s
ongoing malaise has reignited the old debate over which form of government
produces better economic performance.
It is a
discussion in which the supporting evidence seems to have oscillated from one
side to the other in recent decades.
In the
1980s, economic performance in Chile under General Augusto Pinochet’s
dictatorship and in Singapore under the more benign but nonetheless
authoritarian Lee Kuan Yew, was impressive.
Meanwhile,
the democratic countries of the industrialized world struggled against
recession and stagnation. In Europe, this gave rise to the term
“Eurosclerosis.”
Democracies,
according to political scientists, were vulnerable to growth-constraining
special interests.
Authoritarian
regimes - at least those not committed to pillaging their countries - might be
better positioned to implement policies that ensure long-term economic success.
This view crumbled with the fall of the Berlin Wall.
The
collapse of Communism and the renunciation of central planning in Eastern Europe
gave rise to a new line of thinking, as large numbers of voters demonstrated
that they were ready to accept temporary sacrifices if they were linked to a
realistic and non-corrupt reform program.
In Latin
America, left-wing politicians embraced market principles as the best way to
satisfy their constituents’ aspirations, and growth resumed. For much of the
1990s, democracies seemed to have the upper hand.
But the
tug-of-war continues. Since the beginning of this century, China’s supercharged
economic growth once again seemed to highlight the benefits of
authoritarianism.
The Chinese
Communist Party’s success in navigating the turbulence of the global economic
crisis with barely a shudder has attracted the attention of others who would
follow its example.
Leaders
like Russia’s Vladimir Putin, Turkey’s Recep Tayyip Erdogan, Egypt’s Abdel
Fatah el-Sisi and Hungary’s Viktor Orban claim that the price of economic
stability and growth might sometimes be the suspension of democracy.
The
seemingly endless euro crisis has led some European leaders to give credence to
that viewpoint.
At the
start of the crisis, Jean-Claude Juncker, now president of the European
Commission, is reputed to have said, “We all know what to do, we just don’t
know how to get reelected after we’ve done it.”
In May
2010, the European leaders decided that they could not enforce reform in Greece
on their own and called in the International Monetary Fund less as a financial
resource than as a disciplining mechanism.
More
recently, German Finance Minister Wolfgang Schauble sparked controversy when,
evidently drawing inspiration from that experience, he said that France “would
be glad if someone could force the parliament” to reform.
The truth,
of course, is that authoritarian systems - whatever their short-term successes
in holding the line against irresponsible policies - are unsustainable in the
long run.
A lack of
accountability inevitably produces corruption and inefficiency - problems with
which China is now wrestling.
The
challenge for democracies is to develop mechanisms that allow them to set
policies that are sustainable in the long term while safeguarding the
democratic process itself.
The public
consensus supporting difficult reforms in Eastern Europe in the 1990s
demonstrates that voters are able to understand and accept tradeoffs when they
have no perceived alternative. (Likewise, the crisis in Greece shows that
voters will refuse to make sacrifices if they think there is another way out).
Parliamentary
debate is an effective way to set long-term priorities but politicians need to
ensure that the decisions taken are carried out without excessive tinkering or
backtracking.
In the
aftermath of the Great Depression, for example, there was a widespread consensus
in the United States that excessive congressional interference was responsible
for the disastrous hike in import barriers under the Smoot-Hawley Tariff.
Trade
policy, it was decided, was better delegated to the president, an office better
insulated from electoral pressures.
Similarly,
the European debate over appropriate fiscal frameworks might be most
appropriately settled by a referendum, following public debate on a long-term
and sustainable strategy. But the implementation of the decision would be best
entrusted to the member states.
Whether at
the European level or in individual member states, the authority for ensuring
long-term economic growth should be precisely and clearly delegated to agencies
that derive their legitimacy from the democratic process, while being protected
from its baser whims.
The
sustainable alternative to democratic decision-making is not authoritarianism;
it is the implementation of mechanisms that ensure that cool-headed
deliberation is not undermined by the heated response to an immediate crisis.
(Πηγή: ejinsight.com)
Δεν υπάρχουν σχόλια:
Δημοσίευση σχολίου